Subsidies: When Governments Pay to Play (and Keep Others Away)
Discover how government subsidies and administrative barriers affect global trade! Perfect guide for IB Economics students with real examples and exam tips.
IB ECONOMICS HLIB ECONOMICSIB ECONOMICS SLIB ECONOMICS THE GLOBAL ECONOMY / INTERNATIONAL TRADE
Lawrence Robert
5/1/20256 min read


Subsidies: When Governments Pay to Play (and Keep Others Away)
Today we're unpacking subsidies and those administrative barriers that countries use to give their local businesses a leg up. Trust me, this stuff is everywhere in the real world right now!
Subsidies: The Government's Cash Handouts
Imagine your rich aunt secretly slipping you a tenner every time you need to buy lunch so you can compete with your mate who has a part-time job. That's essentially what governments do with subsidies - they hand cash to domestic companies to help them compete against foreign rivals.
Unlike tariffs or quotas (which we've covered in previous posts), subsidies don't stop imports directly. Instead, they're like financial steroids for local businesses, making them stronger competitors on the global playing field.
Types of Subsidies (Because Not All Free Money is Created Equal)
Production Subsidies: The Common One
These are straight-up payments to lower domestic firms' production costs. Think of the UK government handing cash to British Steel to keep it competitive against Chinese imports.
In 2023, the EU approved €2.6 billion in subsidies to European microchip manufacturers to compete with Asian rivals. This isn't just boring economics - it's about who makes the chips for your PlayStation and iPhone!
Export Subsidies: The Controversial One
This is when governments pay domestic companies to sell their products abroad. The EU's infamous agricultural export subsidies helped European farmers dump cheap products in African markets, devastating local agriculture there.
(Side note: These are so controversial that the WTO has mostly banned them, but countries often find ways around the rules!)
How Production Subsidies Work: The South Korean Grain Example
Let's look at South Korea, which subsidises its rice farmers to compete with cheaper imports from Thailand and Vietnam:
Before the subsidy:
World price for grain is PW
Domestic producers can only supply Q1 at this price
Consumers demand Q3 at this price
The difference (Q3 - Q1) is imported
After the subsidy:
Domestic supply curve shifts down (PS to PW)
Domestic supply increases from Q1 to Q2
Imports decrease from (Q3 - Q1) to (Q3 - Q2)
Domestic producers still sell at world price (PW) but receive higher effective price (PS) thanks to government cash
Who Wins and Loses with Subsidies?
Consumers
Unlike with tariffs and quotas, consumers don't immediately feel the pain with subsidies:
You still pay the world price (PW)
You still buy the same amount (Q3)
Your only "change" is buying more domestic products and fewer imports
But wait - is that Korean rice really as good as Thai jasmine rice? That's the hidden cost - potentially lower quality or less variety.
Domestic Producers
Local businesses are absolutely buzzing when subsidies roll in:
They can sell more product (Q1 to Q2)
They get a higher effective price per unit
Their revenues skyrocket
They face less competition
For example, when the UK subsidised renewable energy producers, domestic wind farm companies saw their profits double!
Foreign Producers
Foreign companies aren't invited to the subsidy party:
They sell less to your country
Their revenues drop
They might file complaints to the WTO (like Canada did when the US subsidised its lumber industry)
Government (and Taxpayers)
Unlike tariffs that generate revenue, subsidies cost governments a fortune:
They have to pay (PS - PW) × Q2 to domestic producers
This money must come from somewhere (hello, higher taxes!)
There's a major opportunity cost - this money could build hospitals or schools instead
Recent example: The UK's post-Brexit farm subsidies cost about £2.4 billion annually. That's roughly £36 per UK citizen each year just to support farmers!
Society Overall
Economists agree that subsidies create inefficiencies:
They keep uncompetitive firms alive (like life support for zombie companies)
Resources aren't allocated optimally
The triangular welfare loss area (area c in your diagram) represents the economic waste
Let's Crunch Some Real Numbers: The Potato Subsidy Saga
The Irish government introduces a €2 per unit subsidy on domestically produced potatoes. Let's see how the numbers stack up:
World potato price: €4 per kilogram (unchanged)
Consumer demand: 900,000 kg (unchanged)
Domestic supply: Increases from 500,000 kg to 600,000 kg
Imports: Decrease from 400,000 kg to 300,000 kg
For domestic producers:
Pre-subsidy revenue: €4 × 500,000 = €2 million
Post-subsidy revenue: €6 × 600,000 = €3.6 million
Revenue increase: €1.6 million (nice one!)
For foreign producers:
Pre-subsidy revenue: €4 × 400,000 = €1.6 million
Post-subsidy revenue: €4 × 300,000 = €1.2 million
Revenue decrease: €400,000 (ouch!)
For the government:
Subsidy cost: €2 × 600,000 = €1.2 million
That's €1.2 million that could have funded schools or hospitals!
Export Subsidies: When Governments Pay You to Sell Abroad
Export subsidies are like production subsidies' more aggressive cousin. Let's use the bizarre case of "German bananas" (a hypothetical example, since Germany isn't exactly known for its tropical fruit production!):
The German government wants to boost banana exports to the Netherlands, so they offer a per-unit subsidy to German banana producers who export.
The effects are wild:
Domestic price increases from PWORLD to P2
German consumers buy fewer bananas (Q1 to Q3)
German producers grow more bananas (Q2 to Q4)
Exports increase massively from (Q2 - Q1) to (Q4 - Q3)
German consumers pay more for the same product (bananas)
This is why export subsidies are particularly controversial - they hurt domestic consumers while helping producers!
Recent example: While direct export subsidies are increasingly rare due to WTO rules, China's alleged subsidies to its steel industry allowed Chinese companies to flood global markets with cheap steel, devastating steel industries in Europe and the US.
Administrative Barriers: The Devious Trade Protection
Not all trade protection is about money. Sometimes it's about paperwork and regulations!
What Are They?
Administrative barriers are regulations, standards, and bureaucratic procedures that make it harder for foreign companies to sell in your market.
Think of them as the nightclub bouncer who lets locals skip the queue but makes foreigners fill out forms, show three forms of ID, and explain why they deserve to enter.
Real-World Examples (That Affect Your Life!)
EU Food Standards: The EU bans hormone-treated beef from the US, citing health concerns. Is it really about health, or protecting European farmers? 🤔
Japanese Car Inspections: Japan's extraordinarily complex car inspection system just happens to make importing foreign cars extremely difficult and expensive.
UK Post-Brexit Regulations: Since Brexit, UK exporters face mountains of new paperwork to sell to the EU, with food products needing special certificates. Many small UK businesses have simply stopped exporting!
Chinese Tech Requirements: China requires foreign tech companies to store all Chinese user data on servers located in China and share their source code. Many Western companies have pulled out rather than comply.
The Ultimate Administrative Barrier: Embargoes
Embargoes are the nuclear option of trade policy - completely banning trade with certain countries.
Current examples include:
US embargo on Cuba (since the 1960s!)
International sanctions on North Korea
Various sanctions on Russia following its invasion of Ukraine
These rarely benefit consumers (who lose access to products) but are usually politically motivated rather than economically driven.
Why This Matters for Your IB Exams
Examiners adore questions about subsidies and administrative barriers, especially:
Comparing different forms of protection (subsidies vs. tariffs vs. quotas)
Calculating the welfare effects of subsidies (HL students, I'm looking at you!)
Discussing the hidden impacts of non-tariff barriers
Evaluating which stakeholders gain and lose from different policies
Pro tip: When discussing subsidies in your exams, remember to:
Draw clear diagrams (with proper labelling!)
Calculate numerical effects where possible
Analyse impacts on ALL stakeholders, not just the obvious ones
Link to real-world examples (including recent ones!)
Discuss both economic AND political motivations
The Bottom Line
While subsidies might seem like a "nicer" form of protection than tariffs or quotas (after all, nobody's directly blocking trade), they still create market distortions and inefficiencies. They're like giving someone crutches instead of teaching them to walk properly - they might help in the short term but create dependency in the long run.
Administrative barriers are even trickier because they often hide behind legitimate-sounding concerns like consumer safety or environmental protection. They're the passive-aggressive notes of the trade policy world!
Next time you hear a politician promising to "support domestic industry," look carefully at what they're actually proposing. Is it a subsidy? What will it cost? Who really benefits? Your newfound economics knowledge lets you see beyond the political jargon!
Stay well


























IB Complete Support Courses, a new generation of affordable support materials directed at IB students seeking grades 6 or 7.
© Theibtrainer.com 2012-2025. All rights reserved.